לאחרונה נושא המגבלות
על העברת הון צף שוב לכותרות (רוסיה והקריפטו), ובחודש
שעבר קרן המטבע גם עדכנה (באופן לא משמעותי מספיק) את המדיניות שלה בנושא. הסקירה
שלהלן נוצרה על ידי לפני כמה שנים (כחלק
מעבודה אקדמית) – החלק הראשון כלכלי יותר והשני סקירה משפטית בנושא זה:
1. The negative consequences of capital
liberalization
Much has been written about the efficiency and
aggregate growth that globalization has brought but in recent years economists
have become increasingly aware that unrestrained capital flows may sometimes
lead to the opposite result - the "contagious effect", that spread
the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) through financial linkages, has focused on
the need for capital controls in times of emergency, however, studies show that
uncontrolled capital flows have adverse economic effects even in more calm
times. Economists have found that the effect of FDI on the balance of payments
in the long term may actually be negative, due to "high import content of foreign
firms and profit remittances",[1]and that
"Capital account liberalization episodes have statistically significant
and long-lasting effects on income inequality" [2].
Yet, while there are
still disagreements about the benefits and necessity of capital restrictions to
solve the problems above, there is a broader consensus with regard to a problem
called "hot money".
2.1 "Hot money"- description
Hot money[3] is
short-term speculative investments, mainly through bonds, derivatives and
short-term loans. Incoming hot-money will usually cause: asset prices in the
receiving country to rise, inflation, "credit boom" and an
appreciation of the currency which will harm competition. When hot-money leaves it leads to the opposite -
fast depreciation in the value of assets (especially in countries without
liquid international assets) and currency.
Studies have shown[4] a
significant increase in capital fluctuations and volatility in exchange rates
in recent years, due to this phenomenon.
2.2 Hot-money and the monetary policy of the developed
countries
Recently it has become
increasingly clear that one of the main causes of hot-money is the monetary
policy of the developed countries - especially the unconventional one. The
current economic reality of weak aggregate demand (due to aging and slowing
productivity), globalization, high debt and low inflation, led to greater use
of expansionary monetary policy and due to low interest rate – of quantitative
easing (QE)[5]. These policy measures intend to restore growth
and increase employment in the developed country but at the same time creates a
number of effects on the developing countries, which, as detailed below, are
not necessarily predictable or uniform[6]:
The first effect is
that the increase in domestic demand in the developed country leads to imports
from the developing countries. However, this depends on the elasticity of
demand for imports in the developed country, and in addition increases the
price of imports to the developing countries (the opposite effect). Therefore,
the total outcome for the developing country depends on whether it is a
"net exporter" and on the strength of trade ties with the developed
country. Thus, for example, while reducing the interest rate in the US (or QE)
may actually mean increasing net exports for China, it may have negative
effects on other developing countries with which the US has weaker trade ties.
The second effect is on
the exchange rate - the expansionary policy in the developed country (or
reduction of interest rate) creates a flow of capital to the developing country
and appreciation of its currency. Later expectation of an increase in the
interest rate in the developed country will lead, as noted, to capital outflow
and currency devaluation. This for example is what happened in the East Asian
crisis in 1997.
The third effect is
liquidity. The expansionary policy in the developed country leads to strong
liquidity in the receiving country, but theoretically there should be a counter
–influence so the effect is not entirely clear although empirically based.
Therefore, the overall
effect of the expansionary policy of the developed country on the developing
countries is not uniform and
depends on a number of variables, as well as on the nature of the receiving
countries.
2.3 Sovereign default and Monetary Sovereignty
It is quite clear[7] though,
that poorer countries have fewer tools to deal with such spillovers and this
due to weaker institutions to predict them and weaker "safety nets". Such countries (and stronger ones) may eventually find
themselves in a crisis leads to sovereign default or dependent on the aid of
others as Lenders of Last Resort. Pistor[8] explains that in our credit-based financial global systems most states
"compromise their sovereignty by permitting unlimited capital inflows
denominated in currencies other than their own".
Due to "recognition
and enforcement of foreign law", in the time of crises (and claims),
countries don’t have the access to the money needed to serve sovereign debt
(they don't have enough foreign exchange reserves and cannot print "state
money" due to hyperinflation) and are in fact beholden to many private
money holders and issuers too big to fail.
These countries can only hope for help from other countries in order to
avoid collapse of their financial systems. However, they can rely on such help
only if they themselves pose a threat to global stability. This harms the
sovereignty of the state and subordinates it to those entities or countries which could force it to seek help ex post. Therefore, capital
liberalization and the legal system are in fact undermining the sovereignty of
many countries that are forced to absorb the external effects of the global
financial institutions from the developed countries. Pistor raises an important point, since, as the famous Corfu Channel case[9] emphasizes: "sovereignty is a notion that 'has
its foundation in national sentiment and in the psychology of the peoples".
However, Rodrik[10] stresses
that this is not just a political issue, but that neo-liberalism has been
proven as bad economy, exemplifies China and other countries that flourished as
a result of globalization, but only because they knew how to limit capital
flows. The same point was raised by Stiglitz[11] earlier
when he noted that that Chile “is an example of a success of combining
markets with appropriate regulation” and that in the early years of its
move to neoliberalism, Chile imposed “controls on the inflows of capital, so
they wouldn’t be inundated”.
In sum, capital liberalization has inevitable economic
and other consequences for many countries, especially those to which capital
flows. In an age of high debt and limited fiscal policy there is a growing
consensus that there is an inevitable need to limit such flows through legal
means called capital controls.
2. Capital controls
3.1 Types of Capital Controls
It is common to distinguish[12] between
capital controls that “discriminate on the basis of residency” and
macro-prudential measures that "discriminate" on the basis of
currency in order to maintain stability. The first type includes, inter alia:
foreign ownership restrictions (on domestic companies), restrictions on foreign
loans and acquisitions, restrictions on FDIs and activity in the financial
market, taxes on incoming capital and restrictions on the investment period of
foreign investors or URRs (unremunerated reserve
requirements). The second includes,
inter alia: loan-to-value and debt-to-income regulations, restrictions on
maturity of liabilities and restrictions on derivatives position, caps on asset
acquisition and financial institution's foreign exchange positions and lending,
loan to-deposit ratio limits, and taxes on foreign exchange transactions. Another
distinction is between direct controls through administrative measures, such as
restrictions, quotas and approvals, and between indirect controls - designed to
make capital transfers more expensive - such as taxes and multi exchange rates
for various transactions. The latter type is considered more efficient
economically, because it involves less distortionary costs and makes it
difficult to evade and to manipulate classification in order to circumvent
quotas or prohibitions.
3.2 Examples of capital controls use
Economists estimate that Malaysia survived [13] Asia's 1997 crisis better than its neighbors due to capital
controls. India responded to the US intention to end its QE policy and the
Reserve Bank of India set a three-year holding period for foreign investment in
order to avoid the expected damage from the capital flow. In 2010, Brazil imposed a tax on financial transactions tax with the
aim of reducing incoming flow. China has recently tightened its capital
controls (outwards) by limiting bank account transfers abroad (which may have
affected housing prices in Australia). On the other hand, a recent proposal was
made in the United States to impose some sort of capital control by increasing
the taxation on Chinese investors, as part of the so-called trade war and the
alleged exchange rate manipulations previously attributed to China[14].Greece
imposed restrictions on the transfer of money to foreign banks and on
withdrawals of money in ATMs in order to cope with running to the bank during
its economic crisis in 2015 and similar restrictions was imposed in Cyprus,
another European Union member, for several years following the
crisis in 2013.
Iceland[15] may be an example of a small country (a member of the European Free
Trade Area but not the European Union) that has not given up its monetary
sovereignty, and when it found itself in a crisis simply let its banks fall.
Due to the large capital inflows to the country, Iceland found itself, during
the 2008 GFC, with large external debt of local banks but with tiny foreign
exchange reserves. As stated, Iceland allowed its banks to fall but avoided
default only because it imposed significant capital controls: it amended its Act
No 87/1992 on Foreign Exchange (FX Act) - to allow only current account
transactions and to limit potential cross-border transactions of the estates of
its failed banks – and, later, it enacted another law to impose a high
"stability" tax on these estate funds in case a creditors arrangement
was not reached. This move eventually led to an arrangement with the foreign
creditors and the removal of the capital controls.
Capital controls play
therefore an important role to ensure financial stability and have been imposed
and still imposed by countries in crises and before.
3.3 Cons of Capital Controls
There is no doubt that
well-managed globalization[16] has economic advantages and that total isolation
is neither desirable (economically) nor feasible. However, partial controls
also have disadvantages that need to be considered. As mentioned, capital
controls - mainly the direct ones – not only has domestic distortionary costs but
also spillovers[17] on other developing countries (that will absorb
the flows). For example, some argued[18] that this
could be the case if Turkey would impose more severe controls which will
lead to emerging market contagion.
Capital controls depend on the
discretion of the regulator and therefore involve uncertainty as to the timing
of their imposition or removal, which creates uncertainty among investors.[19] Correlation
was also found with corruption due to the economic impact and attempts to
circumvent the restrictions, especially in developing countries[20]. Another common argument is that granting legitimacy to
the imposition of capital controls will lead to a slippery slope and will allow
restrictions by some countries for competitive reasons, such as control of
firms or intellectual property.[21] However, there are also counter arguments against all
these[22].
3. The IMF institutional view on capital controls
Naturally, the official position of the IMF has
evolved and changed since its establishment: During the Bretton Woods period the
fund members used Capital Controls[23],but in the
last decades of the globalization boom, the IMF has expressed an unfavorable
view of their use.[24] This position changed again in 2010, after several countries
reacted to the expansionary monetary policy of countries such as the US,
England, and Japan, and in 2012 the fund
has released a new institutional view[25] on capital
controls. The position is now
more liberal regarding the regulation of incoming capital flows (outflows only
in times of severe crisis and as a supplementary measure), but emphasizes that
the use should be made only after the macroeconomic policy has been exhausted,
and only temporarily. In addition, the fund distinguishes macro-prudential
measures and other Capital Controls, and advocates that the latter be imposed
only in times of crisis. This position of the
IMF reflects its understanding that large short term foreign capital flows may
have negative implications such as appreciation of the domestic currency,
accumulation of excessive foreign exchange reserves and inflation and financial
instability due to assets bubbles. This position is criticized[26] tough, mainly because it does not provide a
sufficient solution for relatively small developing countries. Another
criticism is with regard to the distinction between the two types of capital
control, which is sometimes unclear or justified and overlap. It seems that the
IMF position is still developing with the findings of recent economic studies.
4. The international legal framework
5.1 The IMF Articles of Agreement[27]
The IMF Articles determine
its mandate and bind its members on condition of receiving assistance. Article
VI: require capital liberalization (of payments only) and allows each member to
exercise capital controls "as are necessary to regulate international
capital movements, but no member may exercise these controls in a manner which
will restrict payments for current transactions …"
The term
"payments" is defined in Art XXX(d) to include: (1)"all payments due in connection with foreign trade,
other current business, including services, and normal short term banking and
credit facilities;(2) ... due as interest on loans and as net income ..;(3) …
amortization of loans or for depreciation of direct investments; (4) moderate
remittances for family living expenses".
The Article also states that "A member may not use the Fund's
general resources to meet a large or sustained outflow of capital … and the
Fund may request a member to exercise controls to prevent such
use".
The IMF Articles do not
allow the fund to condition the provision of assistance to its members in
account liberalization, but in practice there is pressure to do so in order to
obtain a "seal of approval" from the fund or it is done in the
framework of consultation and supervision.[28]
It is worth noting that
the Articles also refer to " Obligations Regarding Exchange Arrangements" and that Article IV provides that: “In particular, each
member shall . . . (iii) avoid manipulating exchange rates or the international
monetary system in order to prevent effective balance of payments adjustment or
to gain unfair competitive advantage over other members . . .”
Some claim[29] that regulating
capital movements, regardless of the intent or purpose, can also affect the exchange
rate and can be interpreted as “manipulation”. Such classification may also be
of importance to any contract that contradicts the capital restrictions, and
this due to Article VIII(2)(b) (Avoidance of restrictions on current payments)
which provides that :(b) Exchange contracts … which are contrary to the
exchange control regulations of that member ... shall be unenforceable in the
territories of any member".
Courts around the world
have adopted two different approaches[30] to Article
VIII(2)(b) - the narrow approach of the US courts (in which the developed
countries favor), whereby only a contract "which entail the exchange of
one currency for another ... shall be unenforceable" (as in Libra
Bank v. Banco Nacional de Costa Rica[31]) and the broader approach (in developing
countries and in Europe in the past).
5.2 The OECD Code of Liberalization of Capital Movements
The OECD Code is a "multilateral agreement on
capital flow management and liberalization…"[32] It is binding for the OECD countries, and since 2012 is also open to
non-OECD countries. The code applies to all long-and short-term capital
movements between residents of OECD countries and it covers also FDIs (in addition, the OECD Code of
Liberalization of Current Invisible Operations[33] cover
cross-border trade for some sectors among them banking and financial services).
The OECD Member countries waived their right to maintain capital controls under
Article VI of the IMF Agreement, however in its updated introduction part it
states that:
"The Code recognizes that capital controls can
play a role in specific circumstances. But because “beggar-thy-neighbor”
approaches can have negative collective outcomes, countries have agreed under
the Code to well-tested principles such as transparency, non-discrimination,
proportionality and accountability to guide their recourse to controls."
In its investment
policy[34] guides,
the OECD has given special reference to "a framework for coping with short-term capital flow
volatility" and it was explained that each participating country was
given the option to object to parts of the code according to its level of
development, and that even without such reservations, steps can be taken
through built-in flexibility clauses to deal with short-term capital flows. In
addition, in 2016, adhering countries adopted terms of reference for a review
of the Code with aim of strengthening it and adapting it to the current
economic situation, and that "a particular area of interest is the
treatment of capital flow measures that are used as macro-prudential
measures". Therefore, it appears that the approach is similar to that
of the IMF.
5.3 EU law
Article 63 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the
European Union (TFEU)[35] prohibits
restrictions on movement of capital and payments between EU member states, and
between EU member states and third countries (Art 63(2)). Article 65 of the
TFEU provides a safeguard on "grounds of public policy or public
security” and Articles 66 and 64 with regard to third parties. Article 347
allows isolating problematic country in order to prevent the contagious effect.
However, it seems that these safeguards allow Capital Controls only in times of
crisis.
During the crises of Iceland (not EU member) a request
was made to the EFTA court by an Icelandic citizen of the United Kingdom to
declare that the capital control measures exercised by Iceland (prevented him
from transferring Icelandic krónur, to Iceland)
contradicts the provisions of Article 43 to The Agreement between the EFTA
States on the Establishment of a Surveillance Authority (EEA Agreement). This Article contains similar safeguards and provides
that:
(2) If movements of capital lead to disturbances in
the functioning of the capital market in any EC Member State or EFTA State, the
Contracting Party concerned may take protective measures in the field of
capital movements. ... (4) Where an EC Member State or an EFTA State is in
difficulties, …as regards its balance of payments … the Contracting Party
concerned may take protective measures"
The EFTA Court held[36] that given
the circumstances (Iceland sought to stabilize the króna
and the foreign exchange reserves) the controls were compatible with the above
provisions.
5.4 GATS
Under The General Agreement on Trade in Services
(GATS) WTO members must open their capital account with regard to a covered
service (as capital transactions are associated with financial service).
Under mode 1 - a service provided from one country to another - they must allow
inward and outward movements of capital and under mode 3 - commercial presence
in the other country - the host country must allow inward capital movements. However,
Article XII allows "Restrictions to Safeguard the Balance-of-Payment"
under the following limitations " (a) shall not discriminate..;
(b) shall be consistent with the Articles of Agreement of the International
Monetary Fund; (c) shall avoid unnecessary damage ..; (d) shall not exceed
those necessary to deal with the circumstances ..; (e) shall be temporary ...".
Therefore, there is ambiguity regarding the
possibility of imposing effective capital controls under these restrictions, in
particular in view of the "necessary" and "temporary"
requirements. In addition to the balance and payments safeguard, Article 2(a)
of the Annex on financial services[37] provides "prudential carve-out" as follows: "...a Member shall not be prevented
from taking measures for prudential reasons, including for the protection of
investors, depositors, policy holders or persons to whom a fiduciary duty is
owed by a financial service supplier, or to ensure the integrity and stability
of the financial system. Where such measures do not conform with the
provisions of the Agreement, they shall not be used as a means of avoiding the
Member's commitments or obligations under the Agreement". Again,
ambiguity regarding the end of the section, and it is not clear whether it can
be regarded as a self-cancellation. However, in Argentina – Financial
Services (2016) - which dealt with the circumstances of restricting access
to Argentina's stock and insurance market (in the context of tax avoidance
cooperation) - the Appellate Body[38] held, with regard to the above last sentence in the prudential
carve-out, that "The reference to 'the provisions of the Agreement'
suggests that this sentence also relates to inconsistencies with any other
provision of the GATS" – that is that prudential reasons allow for
deviations from any commitment in the agreement, including "for example, a Member's most-favoured-nation treatment obligation under Article II,
market access commitments under Article XVI, or national treatment obligation
under Article XVII". The Appellate Body also discussed the meaning of
the term "for prudential reasons" and held that the
requirement of necessity and temporality in Article XII does not apply to
Article 2(a) of the Annex.
Bilateral trade (FTAs) and investment agreements
(BITS)
Many countries are parties to trade and investment
agreements, which often include a commitment to greater liberalization than the
above-mentioned multilateral agreements - whether due to more extensive types
of payments and transactions covered by these agreements, or due to more
restricted carve-out and safeguards. In addition, many of the agreements
include a mechanism of investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) which allows
foreign investors to force arbitration proceedings on the state that imposed
capital controls.
For example, in El Paso Energy International
Company v. Argentine[39] an American company
claimed that Argentina's capital controls during the economic crisis, including
taxation on outflows, contravene the investment treaty with the US and
constitute expropriation of its property. The Tribunal ruled in its favor. The Belgium and
Luxembourg-Malaysia BIT was also the subject of investor's claim (Gruslin v. Malaysia[40]) against
Malaysia due to the exchange controls measures taken by it during the economic
crisis (which he claimed caused him losses on the stock exchange).
In a recent G-24 working paper Gallagher et al[41] offer to map the various treaties in the international
arena according to the level of flexibility in which they allow the use of
Capital Controls. They find that art differs in several key parameters among
them: the commitment to liberalize current and capital
transfers and its scope, the existence of safeguards against balance of
payments crises, the limitation of the scope of a “prudential measures” and
ISDS procedure.
In addition, they mention that most of the new
treaties include a most-favored-nation clause (MFN) that obligates a party to
extend its best treatment of other partners to other treaties, to each other as
long as it relates to a matter covered by the treaty. Therefore, and despite the above decision in Argentina
– Financial Services case, this article may be interpreted as preventing
restrictions on capital controls despite the provisions of specific treaty (but
in any case will apply only if capital flows covered by the specific treaty and
will not expand the possibility of ISDS[42]).
Their findings indicate
that more new treaties are making it difficult to impose capital controls as
a result of the stronger power of developed countries in negotiating agreements
with developing countries.
5.5 U.S agreements
The US FTAs and BITs
usually does not allow the use of capital controls, for example, Article 7 of the 2012 U.S. Model Bilateral Investment
Treaty provides that: "Each Party shall permit all transfers
relating to a covered investment to be made freely and without delay into
and out of its territory" and Article 6 which deals with
expropriation is used by American investors to force (in privet) countries into
arbitration due to their use of Capital Controls. Article 20: Financial
Services provide prudential curve-out but the term prudential is defined as
"maintenance of the safety, .. of individual
financial institutions, as well as the maintenance of the safety and
financial and operational integrity of payment and clearing systems"
and similar clauses in the trade and investment treaties signed were
interpreted as not allowing the imposition of capital controls. Although in some treaties there is an appendix that
allows the stay of the investor's claim, but this does not detract from the
deterrence of the countries to use Capital Controls. Therefore, scholars[43] have
criticized this position, inter alia, for requiring discrimination between
American investors and other investors, and sometimes even against the IMF's
Articles to the extent that a certain country is required by the IMF to use capital
controls.
5.6
New Mega Trade Agreements
Trade and
investment agreements with the European Union[44]
EU countries
are leading exporters of financial services and therefore have an interest in
including these services in the trade agreements and in liberalizing the
capital flows associated with them. Finance Watch[45]
report illustrates how the EU is pushing for liberalization of the new trade
agreements at the expense of Capital Controls. For example, the integration of
financial services in the proposed Trade in Services Agreement (TISA) and the
"regulatory cooperation" and transparency provisions may prevent
countries from applying capital controls. The EU proposed limiting the
prudential curve out so that: “measures shall not be more burdensome than
necessary to achieve their aim”. A similar "necessity" limitation was
raised during the negotiations on Japan-EU Free Trade Agreement (JEFTA) but was
rejected by the Japanese. The JEFTA uses the method of negative lists which
requires total liberalization, with the exception of services explicitly
mentioned. This is problematic in terms of restricting new and innovative
financial services. A similar method was taken in the Comprehensive Economic
and Trade Agreement - EU/Canada (CETA) and in this agreement there is also
another problem- the ISDS mechanism which exposes the countries to arbitration
proceedings and thus creates uncertainty and makes it difficult for Capital
Controls.
The obligation to review the regulation before approval of the
proceedings is not expected to be helpful in situations of disagreement among
the regulators (article 13.20 and 21). The report points out that in CETA the
controls safeguard (article 28.4) is
broader than the existing provisions in other agreements and allows for
measures in case of “cause or threaten to cause serious difficulties for the
operation of the economic and monetary union of the European Union.”
USMCA and TPP[46]
These
agreements are in line with the liberalization trend in the above-mentioned
trade agreements, but also include "Exchange Rate Matters" clause (in
Chapter 33 of the USMCA) identical to Article IV of the IMF. Although this
clause is intended to prevent the devaluation of the local currency - usually
the opposite of what is caused by Capital Control - some believe that it may
harm the use of capital controls due to the possible sanctions[47].
[1] Yilmaz Akyuz (2015), “Foreign Direct Investment, Investment
Agreements and Economic Development: Myths and Realities”, South Centre
Research Paper #63, page 1. Available on:
https://www.southcentre.int/research-paper-63-october-2015/#more-7895.
[2] Furceri, Davide & Loungani, Prakash. (2017), "The
distributional effects of capital account liberalization". Journal of
Development Economics. 130
[3] See Yan, Cheng, Hot Money in Disaggregated Capital Flows
(November 27, 2017). European Journal of Finance, Forthcoming. Available at
SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3077936
[4] John B. Taylor Capital Flows, the IMF's Institutional View, and
An Alternative Remarks
at the Policy Conference “Currencies, Capital, and Central Bank
Balances” Hoover Institution
Stanford University May 4, 2018
[5] Lynch, David J. "Bernanke's 'Cheap Money' Stimulus Spurs
Corporate Investment Outside U.S". (17 November 2010). Bloomberg.
[6] Blanchard, Olivier J., Currency Wars, Coordination, and Capital Controls
(July 2016). Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper No.
16-9. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2808693 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2808693
[7] Mishra, Prachi and Raghuram Rajan (2018), “Rules of the Monetary
Game” paper presented at the Policy Conference “Currencies, Capital, and
Central Bank Balances,” Hoover Institution, Stanford University
[8] Pistor, Katharina, From Territorial to Monetary Sovereignty
(August 14, 2018). Theoretical Inquiries in Law, Vol. 18, Iss. 2, pp. 491 to
517, July 2017; Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper No. 591. Available at
SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3251397 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3251397
[9] Corfu Channel, United Kingdom v Albania, Judgment, Merits, ICJ GL No 1,
[1949] ICJ Rep 4, ICGJ 199 (ICJ 1949), 9th April 1949, United Nations [UN];
International Court of Justice [ICJ]
[10] See for
example D. Rodrik, Rescuing
Economics from Neoliberalism, Boston Review, November 6,
2017< http://bostonreview.net/class-inequality/dani-rodrik-rescuing-economics-neoliberalism>
[11] See in Ostry, J., Loungani, P., & Furceri, D. (2016). Neoliberalism:
Oversold?, IMF Finance and Development, Vol. 53, No. 2
[12] See 4 above.
[13]
Did the Malaysian Capital Controls Work?, Ethan Kaplan, Dani Rodrik. in
Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets, Edwards and Frankel. 2002
[14] Senator Marco Rubio, “S.2, 116th Congress (2019-2020): Fair
Trade with China Enforcement Act,"
Congress.gov,January 3, 2019, https://www.congress.gov/bill/116th-congress/senate-bill/2.
"to make more expensive China’s currency intervention, in addition to
reducing extranormal upward pressure on the USD due to China-source investment,
which as discussed in this report, is often not market-based".
[15] Baldursson, Fridrik M. and Portes, Richard and Thorlaksson, Eirikur
Elis, Iceland's Capital Controls and the Resolution of its Problematic Bank
Legacy (July 3, 2017). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2996631
or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2996631
[16]Stiglitz,
Joseph E., 2003. "Globalization and growth in emerging markets and the New
Economy," Journal of Policy Modeling, Elsevier, vol. 25(5), pages 505-524,
July.
[17] Valerio Nispi Landi, 2018. "Capital controls spillovers,"
Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 1184, Bank of Italy, Economic
Research and International Relations Area.
[18] Sam Merdith ‘Full-blown’
capital controls in Turkey could spark emerging market contagion, Goldman Sachs
analyst says" (AUG 2018) CNBC <
https://www.cnbc.com/2018/08/16/turkey-lira-crisis-goldman-sachs-warns-emerging-market-contagion-could-follow-capital-controls.html>
[19]
Gourio, Francois and Siemer, Michael and Verdelhan, Adrien, Uncertainty
and International Capital Flows (August 28, 2015). Available at SSRN:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2626635 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2626635
[20]
Axel Dreher & Lars-H. Siemers, 2009. "The nexus between
corruption and capital account restrictions," Public Choice, Springer,
vol. 140(1), pages 245-265, July.Vol. 140, No. 1/2 (Jul., 2009), pp. 245-265
[21] See Taylor 4 above.
[22] See Dani Rodrik's weblog, Nonsensical arguments against capital
controls (2008) at: <https://rodrik.typepad.com/dani_rodriks_weblog/2008/03/nonsensical-arg.html>
[23] Duncan E. Williams, Policy Perspectives on the Use of Capital
Controls in Emerging Market Nations: Lessons from the Asian Financial Crisis
and a Look at the International Legal Regime, 70 Fordham L. Rev. 561
(2001).
[24] Kevin P. Gallagher Ruling Capital: Emerging Markets and the
Reregulation of Cross-border Finance
Cornell University Press (2015)
[25] International Monetary Fund, The Liberalization and Management
of Capital Flows: An Institutional View, Policy Survey Paper International
Monetary Fund (2012)
[26] Magalhães Prates, Daniela & Farhi, Maryse. (2015). From
IMF to the Troika: new analytical framework, same conditionalities.
Économie et Institutions.
[27] Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund
at<https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/aa/index.htm>
[28] See Duncan E. Williams 23 above.
[29] See Mishra, Prachi and Raghuram Rajan above.
[30] Global Governance of Financial Systems. The International
Regulation of Systemic Risk By Alexander Kern, Dhumale Rahul, and Eatwell John
[OUPOxford New York2006320 pp ISBN 9780195166989 £26.99 (h/bk)]
[31] See, e.g., Banco Do Brasil, S.A. v. A.C. Israel Commodity Co. Inc.,
190 N.E.2d
235
(N.Y.
1963) (endorsing a narrow view of an exchange contract); J. Zeevi & Sons,
Ltd. v. Grindlays Bank (Uganda), Ltd., 333 N.E.2d 168 (N.Y. 1975)
(letter of credit is
not an exchange contract).
[32] OECD (2018), OECD Code of Liberalisation of Capital Movements,
2018<
https://www.oecd.org/daf/inv/investment-policy/Code-capital-movements-EN.pdf>
[33] OECD (2015), OECD Code of Liberalization of Current Invisible
Operations <
https://www.oecd.org/daf/fin/private-pensions/InvisibleOperations_WebEnglish.pdf>
[34] OECD (2015), OECD PROMOTING ORDERLY CAPITAL FLOWS: THE APPROACH OF THE CODE <http://www.oecd.org/daf/inv/investment-policy/CapMovCodeBrochure.pdf
[35] “Consolidated versions of the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union,” European Commission < http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/HTML/?uri=CELEX:12016ME/TXT&from=EN>
[36] Case E-3/11 Sigmarsson v. The Central Bank of Iceland, Judgment of the EFTA Court of 14 December 2011, [2012] 1 CMLR 50.
[37]
See
WTO analytical index GATS – Annex on Financial Services (Jurisprudence)
<https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/ai17_e/gats_annfinancialservices_jur.pdf>
[38] Appellate Body Report, Argentina – Measures Relating to Trade in
Goods and Services, WT/DS453/AB/R and Add.1, adopted 9 May 2016, DSR 2016:II,
p. 431
[39] El Paso Energy International Company v The Argentine Republic -
ICSID Case No. ARB/03/15 -Decision on the Application for Annulment (22
September 2014)
[40] Philippe Gruslin v. Malaysia (Case No. ARB/94/1) 13 January 1994
[41] Kevin P. Gallagher, Sarah Sklar, Rachel Thrasher Quantifying the
Policy Space for Regulating Capital
Flows in Trade and Investment Treaties A G-24 Working
Paper April 2019
[42] See Gallagher et al refer to ADF Group Inc. v. United States of
America, ICSID Case No. ARB (AF)/00/1
[43] See Gallagher et al
[44] With regard to agreements within the EU, it should be noted that
following the Slovak Republic v. Achmea B.V., Case no. C-284/16 judgment
all EU countries undertook to abolish their BITs with other EU c members
[45] Financial Regulation challenged by European Trade Policy, a report
by Veblen Institute for Economic Reforms and Finance Watch (October 2018)
[46] United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (signed) and the proposed rans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
[47] See Neal Kimberley, On China’s ‘currency manipulation’, the US
should be careful what it wishes for, South China Morning Post (October
2018) at <https://www.scmp.com/comment/insight-opinion/united-states/article/2168660/chinas-currency-manipulation-us-should-be>